How To Make Money

This should be common knowledge: capitalist economies are inherently monetary, and you'd think that, after a few centuries of capitalism, we'd understand how money is created. But there are few topics about which there are more myths, and more false answers, than this fundamental question.

Building a New Economics is a reader-supported publication. To receive new posts and support my work, consider becoming a free or paid subscriber.

In fact, there's an easy way to understand how money is created—though "easy" means "easy, once you understand double entry bookkeeping". I'll elaborate below, but the "TL;DR" takeaway is that any operation which increases the Assets of the banking sector creates money.

To understand this, you have to understand double-entry bookkeeping—or DEB for short. It's essential, because it's the way accountants have kept track of financial transactions for centuries, and it's fundamental to how banks operate.

The key rules in DEB is that all transactions are recorded twice, and each row in a DEB table must sum to zero (if it doesn't, you've made a mistake). All accounts are also classified as either Assets, or Liabilities, or Equity, and the "Fundamental Law of Accounting" is that Assets minus Liabilities equals Equity: the gap between what you are owed (Assets) and what you owe (Liabilities) is your net worth (Equity).

In conjunction with my TL;DR rule above—that "anything which increases the assets of the banking sector creates money"—this means that a financial operation that creates money must occur on both the Assets and the Liabilities-Equity side of the banking sector's ledger. Conversely, any operation which occurs only on the Assets side of the banking sector's ledger, or on the Liabilities-Equity side, does not create money.

Now let's check some key financial operations, using a software package I invented for this purpose called Minsky (it's free, and you can download it from here: https://sourceforge.net/projects/Minsky/.

Firstly, bank loans. A bank loan adds an amount to your deposit account at your bank—which is a Liability of the bank—and it adds the identical amount to your loan account at the bank—which is an Asset of the bank. Call the flow of new loans each year "Lending". Then the double-entry bookkeeping is as shown in Figure 1: bank lending increases the Assets of the banking sector, and it therefore creates money—which shows up as an increase in your Deposit account.

Figure 1: "Godley Table" in Minsky showing that bank lending creates money

Repayment has the opposite effect: it reduces bank assets, and it therefore destroys money. This is something that I was wrong about, by the way, before I understood double-entry bookkeeping: I thought that once money was created, banks wouldn't just "destroy" it. But when you look at the double-entry, it's obvious: if you tell the bank to reduce your Deposit account, in return for an identical reduction in your debt to the bank, then precisely that much money is destroyed.

Bank lending is something that economics textbooks get wrong, and in fact, economics textbooks—which should be a source of wisdom on economics—are actually the primary source of myths about money. The Bank of England said this explicitly, if politely, in 2014:

The reality of how money is created today differs from the description found in some economics textbooks: Rather than banks receiving deposits when households save and then lending them out, bank lending creates deposits.
— (McLeay, Radia, and Thomas 2014)

What about government spending and taxation? Spending adds to the public's Deposits, with a matching entry in bank Reserves—which are the deposit accounts of the private banks at the Central Bank. Therefore, government spending also creates money, just as bank loans do—by increasing bank Liabilities (Deposits) and bank Assets (Reserves) by precisely the same amount: see Figure 2.

Figure 2: Government spending creates money, and taxation destroys money

Since Spending minus Taxation equals the government deficit, this means that a government deficit creates money, while a government surplus destroys it.

This is also the opposite of what economics textbooks say: to quote from Mankiw's influential first year economics textbook "When its spending exceeds its revenue, the government runs a budget deficit, which represents negative public saving" (Mankiw 2016, p. 253). But in fact, since the deficit increases Deposit accounts, the deficit represents positive public saving.

Obviously, if economics textbooks teach fallacies and falsehoods, then there's something seriously wrong with economics—and I'll explore that in my next column "How to Mangle Money".

But now, let's look at government borrowing through double-entry bookkeeping eyes. In practice, the government borrows by the Treasury selling Treasury Bonds to the banking sector. Does this create money?

As Figure 3 illustrates, Treasury Bond sales do not create money, because everything happens on the Assets side of the banking sector's ledger: the monetary value of bank holdings of Treasury Bonds rises, but the value of bank Reserves fall by the same amount.

Figure 3: Sales of treasury bonds to banks do not create money

What about Central Bank purchases of Treasury Bonds from the banks? Here, I'll admit another mistake of mine: before I modelled this in Minsky, I thought that Central Bank bond purchases did create money. But as Figure 4 illustrates, they don't, because both operations take place on the Asset side of the banks' ledger: the monetary value of bonds owned by the banks falls, while bank Reserves rise by precisely as much. Therefore, there's no change in the value of bank Assets from Central Bank purchases. Instead, there's an Asset swap.

Figure 4: Central Bank purchases of government bonds do not create money

Of course, government bonds pay interest: this is shown in Figure 5. And this might be another surprise: these interest payments create money, since they increase both the Asset side of the banks' ledger (Reserves) and the Liabilities-Equity side (in this case, the short-term equity of the banking sector).

Figure 5: Interest payments on government bonds do create money

Banks often sell most of the bonds they buy to non-banks—normally, financial institutions like hedge funds, pension funds, insurance companies, etc, rather than the ordinary public. This operation actually destroys money: bank deposits fall, as do bank holdings of Treasury Bonds.

Figure 6: Bank sales of bonds to the Public destroys money

Finally, what about "QE": "Quantitative Easing"? This is the Central Bank buying bonds, and whether it creates money depends on who the Central Bank buys from. If it buys from banks, there's no money creation, as the second-last line in Figure 7 shows. But QE also included buying bonds from non-bank financial institutions. This does create money—but money that circulates on Wall Street, rather than Main Street.

Figure 7: QE doesn't create money when it's with banks, but does when it's with non-banks

Those are the basics, and I hope you agree that it's all pretty simple. But it also contradicts everything you'll find in economics textbooks, and in much of public discourse about how money functions. This is because everything about money in economics textbooks is as wrong as Ptolemaic astronomers once were about the nature of the Universe. It took Galileo's telescope to point out that the models of Earth-centric astronomy were wrong, and economics needs such a telescope today.

Minsky, with its Godley Tables, is that telescope. If you're at all interested in the topics of how money is created, and how much should be created, and by whom, and for whom, please, get your free telescope from https://sourceforge.net/projects/Minsky/. Widespread use of this computerized telescope into money creation may be the only way to finally kill the many myths about money creation.

We are about to release a major update, version 3.0 of Minsky, which will use a more modern Javascript front end, in place of the Linux-based front end the program currently has. That will be announced on my Patreon and Substack accounts (see the footer for the links), but in the meantime, the existing "Tcl/Tk" version works fine, and models you build with it will be compatible with the new version.

There's also a manual for Minsky at http://www.profstevekeen.com/Minsky/.

The first substantive chapter, "Understanding money: "Minsky for Dummies"", guides you to build models that cover the same ground as here, and without an equation in sight—they turn up in the subsequent chapters. So, anyone can use Minsky to model the financial system, as I have done here in very basic detail.

Figure 8: Collating private and government monetary operations

Lastly, you may be wondering where assets like houses, shares, etc. are in the scheme of double-entry things. They are "nonfinancial assets"—assets which are an Asset for their owners, but a Liability to no-one. We have recently extended Minsky to cope with them, by enabling multiple Equity columns, and the capacity to record an entity as both as Asset and a Liability. Figure 9 below shows how they are handled at present, and it also shows Minsky's capacity to build a multi-faceted view of the financial system: all the operations in the Banking sectors tables above are now replicated from the Non-Banking sector's perspective.

Figure 9: The Non-Banking sector's Godley Table, including the non-financial asset of housing

So, if you're at all interested in how to make money—in terms of how the monetary system actually functions—download a copy of Minsky and get cracking. Don't be reticent: Minsky won't bite, and you have nothing to lose but your myths.


REFERENCES

Mankiw, N. Gregory. 2016. Macroeconomics, 9th edition (Macmillan: New York).

  1. McLeay, Michael, Amar Radia, and Ryland Thomas. 2014. 'Money in the modern economy: an introduction', Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, 2014 Q1: 4-13.
Share this post